The
Policy Making Process and Models for Public Policy Analysis
Giovanni E. Reyes
University of
Pittsburgh
Graduate School of Public and International Affairs
1. Introduction (4)
2. The Nature of Public Policy
Problems (5)
2.1. Definitions
2.2. Public and private problems
2.3. Political forces within public problems
2.4. Political systems and problem identification
2.5. A list of major issue-areas
2.6. Issues and events
3. The Policy Making Process (10)
3.1. General features
3.2. Conceptual approaches to study the methodology of policy process
3.3. Defining policy
3.4. A policy process framework
3.4. Theoretical approaches to study the policy making process and main
political
actors -rationalists, technicians, incrementalists, reformists-.
4. Major Models for Public Policy
Analysis (18)
4.1. General
Considerations
4.2. Difference Equations
4.2.1. Description and illustrations
4.2.2. General form of a difference equation
4.2.3. Difference equations of higher order
4.2.4. The use of difference equations in modeling
4.3. Queuing or ranking method
4.3.1. General features
4.3.2. Probabilistic queuing models
4.4. Simulation and non-lineal methods
4.4.1. General features
4.4.2. Macroeconomic simulation
4.4.3. Simulation as an analytical tool
4.5. Markov chains
4.5.1. Markov chains: An example
4.5.2. Main properties of a transition matrix
4.5.3. Regular, absorbing and cyclical
chains
4.6. Cost-Benefit Analysis
4.6.1. Cost-benefit analysis and project evaluation
4.6.2. The procedure
4.7. Linear programming
4.7.1. The elements of a linear programming problem
4.7.2. The limitations of linear programming
5. Public Policy Analysis: A General Methodology
5.1. Establishing the
context
5.2. Determining alternatives
5.3. Establishing the consequences
5.4. Valuing the outcomes
5.5. Determining a choice
6. Bibliography (40)
1. Introduction
The main objective of this document is to present a summary about two major topics: a) the
process to formulate public policy decisions, and
b) the principal methods to evaluate the
impact and effects of a public policy. Both
areas constitute core aspects of public
policy analysis. Here I present their major
characteristics followed by a brief discussion concerning their social implications and
methodology.
The term government is consider here from a Weberian perspective, that it is the
main social institution which gives national social units its coherence, representation,
and a leading role. Its power is based either
on a) tradition; or b) on charismatic features of leaders; or c) on a law and
rationalistic basis. From this perspective,
bureaucracy plays an important role in being a fundamental part of the public sphere, and
its main "technostructural" column. Bureaucratic
power is mainly evident in the stages of implementing and evaluating public policy. [1]
This document has three main parts. At
the beginning we are going to focus on the nature of
public problems, how these problems are different from the private sector problems,
and what are their main repercussions. A good
understanding of this section is pertinent to the comprehension of the next chapters, and
the main sections of this exposition.
The middle section is devoted to the discussion of the process to formulate public
policies. Here it is important to keep in
mind the influence from the real powers in society, namely
the business sector, the international interest, and also some institutions, such
as political organizations, especial interest
groups, churches, universities, and the armed forces.
Complementary it is also important to be aware of the processes derived from the
formal powers in society, namely national officials which are elected to represent society
as a whole in a democratic nation.[2]
The final section will focus on the main methods to study the impact from public
policy decisions. We do not expect to cover
all the methods, but at least to present the fundamental methodologies and their main
features. References respect to the
implementation process for public policy making is presented at the end of this document. I will finish with a general presentation
concerning the methodology for a public policy analysis situation. In this last part the objective is to synthesize
the analytical aspects discussed in the other chapter of this document.
2. The Nature of Public Policy Problems
2.1. Definitions
To understand many of the most important features of public problems, it is
necessary to clarify terms in order to set the context of both the political and social
conditions for public policy analysis. Several
of the most commonly used terms are the following:
a) Events: Human and natural acts
perceived to have social consequences.
b) Problems: Human needs, however
identified, that cannot be met privately.
c) Issues: Controversial public
problems.
d) Issue areas: Bundles of controversial public problems. [3]
Events naturally vary immensely in effect. Wars
and natural disasters touch millions of lives. Inventions
like the internal combustion engine have altered our life-style dramatically. A new family in the neighborhood, however,
normally has only limited consequences.
Events may cause problems to emerge and set the conditions for resolving them. Whether this happens depends on how observers
perceive events. Those directly affected by a
zoning variance that permits construction of a new shopping center and apartment complex,
for example, may identify specific needs created by this event; others affected may not
identify any particular resulting needs. Still
others, perhaps a group of environmentalists not directly affected, may identify a need
for those living in the area and oppose the variance.
Congruity in identifying and acting on needs is by no means guaranteed, and
therefore many problems may result from the same event.
Conflict among problem definitions creates an issue.[4]
2.2. Public and Private Problems
If a problem can be resolved without making demands on the people that are not
immediately affected, then it is private in nature. John
Dewey explains it thus:
"We take then our point
of departure from the objective fact that human acts have consequences upon others, that
some of these consequences are perceived, and that their perception leads to subsequent
effort to control action so as to secure some consequences and avoid others. Following this clew, we are led to remark that the
consequences are of two kinds, those which affect the persons directly engaged in a
transaction, and those which affect others beyond those immediately concerned. In this distinction, we find the germ of the
distinction between the private and the public."[5]
A particular and essential feature of a public problem is the following: Human acts
have consequences on others, and some of these are perceived to create needs to the extent
that relief is sought. If the transaction to
control consequences (regulating needs) is relatively restricted in effect, it is private.
If the transaction has a broad effect, it is public.
According to Dewey, "the public consists of all those who are affected by the
indirect consequences of transactions to such an extent that it is deemed necessary to
have those consequences systematically cared for."
People take actions or propose actions to control their environments: to meet their
needs, to solve their problems. Sometimes
these actions have consequences for others. When
these consequences are perceived by others and considered to be significant enough to be
controlled, we are facing a public problem. As
David G. Smith explains: "That which
intervenes between the perceived problem and the governmental outcome is a public, a group
of affected parties-aroused, engaged in conjoint activity, growing conscious of itself,
organizing and seeking to influence officials."[6]
In a more economic sense oriented, public problems, on the other hand, frequently
involved the production and use of public goods, such as national defense, the national
road system, and the general structure of the academic pensa. Conversely, private problems involved
production and consumption of private goods. Public
goods are goods -and in a broad sense services- that can be used by many people at the
same time. Private goods have as a
fundamental feature, the fact that it is not possible for two persons to use the same
private good at the same time, i.e. personal cloths.[7]
2.3. Political Forces Within Public
Problems
This concept of a public is important for these deliberations. Just as we have made a distinction between public
and private problems, so too we can distinguish between public problems that have a
supporting public and those public problems that do not.
The first type of problem is characterized by a group of concerned and organized
citizens who intend to get action; the second
is acknowledged as a problem that cannot be solved privately, but it lacks organized and
active support.
This distinction is critical for understanding the complex processes by which some
problems reach government and others do not. The
objective verification that a public problem exists (e.g., the many problems of the poor
in most of the more developed nations) is no guarantee that a public will emerge to press
for relief. As it is evident in many cases in
the United States, "Public problems may lack a supporting public among those directly
affected." Yet the government may act due to the demands of others. "Policy makers sometimes define
problems for people who have not defined problems for themselves." This last
condition can present several concrete opportunities for politicians especially during the
political campaign and elections.[8]
Not only are problems private and public supported and non supported, this
discussion shows that a whole bundle of issues may be associated with any one event-for
example, the Arab oil embargo; the hostage crisis in Iran; the rapid growth, then decline,
of the school population; the deregulation of the airlines.
For this reason it is important to introduce the term issue area. What are often referred to as public
problems-education, energy, mass transportation, housing-are in reality various
conflicting demands for relieving several sets of needs among the persons within society. Complicating matters even more is the fact that
needs and demands, and therefore conflicts and priorities, are constantly changing; issues
therefore require almost continual definition and redefinition.[9]
2.4. Political Systems and Problem
Identification
One can distinguish one political system from another by examining the
characteristics of problem identification processes.
In a democratic system problem identification is intended to be more subjective; in
an authoritarian system it is intended to be more objective. In objectively defining problems an effort is made
to employ scientific measures of the effects of events on people (this says nothing about
the success of these measures, of course). [10]
There is little or no reliance on how the people interpret effects of events. Subjective processes, on the other hand, place a
great deal of reliance on how those affected by an event interpret their needs. Elections and other representative processes
presumably tap the public's subjective views. Both
objective and subjective measures are, if
fact, relied on by all political systems.
2.5.
A List of Major Issue Areas
One of the many advantages of an open society -in which a democratic political
systems works, and civil society has an important and permanent influence on national
issues-, is that evaluations of social progress come from a variety of sources. We do not have to await the announcement of a
five-year plan to determine what should be done, like in the former soviet-socialist
countries. We get frequent private and public
assessments. [11]
Often presidents' national discourses
and economic and budget messages, counter programs and messages from legislative branches,
all constitute official evaluations of where we are and what we must do. In addition we in this kind of open societies, can
see any number of critical and analytical reviews from private agencies and interest
groups. In United States, for example, the
Brooking Institution, an independent organization devoted to nonpartisan research, has for
the past several years offered an analysis of the president's budget that has become a
justly respected document. Groups like Common
Cause, a citizen lobby, and the Ralph Nader Center for Study of Responsive Law are devoted
to a kind of government watchdog function, and their reports naturally become source of
information on public problems. [12]
While admittedly not altruistic in their endeavors, many national interest groups
also performs similar functions as they search for policies, problems, and events that may
affect their clienteles. Finally, some groups
can provide data on what problems the general public judges to be important at any one
time.
Taken together these various sources suggest a number of issue-area categories, that is, broad classifications of "bundles of controversial public problems." As a minimum these would include: [13]
Table 1:
Issue-Areas for Public Policy Analysis
No. |
Issue Area |
Examples |
1 |
Foreign |
Relations
with nations (individually and in alliances) |
|
|
Economic
cooperation |
2 |
Defense |
Armed forces |
|
|
Security
cooperation with other nations |
|
|
Arms special
dispositions and treaties |
3 |
Internal
Affairs |
Human
resources, including health, education, welfare and job training |
|
|
Physical and
natural resources |
|
|
Civil rights |
|
|
Social
control and internal security |
|
|
Economic
control |
|
|
Government
organization |
|
|
Taxation |
|
|
Financial
conditions |
|
|
Government
expenditures |
Source: Based on Stokey, E. Public Policy Analysis, Ob.Cit. p.10-12;
and Jones, Ch. Study of Public Policy Analysis,
Ob.Cit. p. 43.
National budgets in different nations reflect one catalog of needs and how those
needs are interpreted as priorities. However,
the accelerated growth of certain budget items, combined with a stagnating economy, has
reduced the capacity of governments to respond to new problems. Some people, including many in the Reagan
administration in United States, conclude that the biggest problem of all is the
rejuvenation of the economy, and that can occur only with a reduction in government
spending and influence -neoliberal social and economic perspective-.
Others doubt that this solution will work and call for increased government control
of the economy -Keynesian, and Neokeynesian option-.
It is apparent that the two groups are in agreement on one point at least: that
certain major problems are not being solved by governments.
Of both sides the budget is not the best inventory of major issue areas, a
conclusion that has placed the budget front and center in the national policy-making
system.[14]
2.6.
Issues and Events
What events have created the needs
leading to major national issues? Again the discussion must be conducted at a general
level and must be designed primarily to explain contemporary trends. According to Charles O. Jones, there are five
broad categories of events influential in shaping issues: events of discovery,
development, communication, conflict, and control. Broadly speaking, these events
constitute what John Dewey calls the "human acts" that "have consequences
upon others." They are the starting
points for tracing the policy process for any one issue. [15]
3.
The Policy Making Process
3.1. General Features
A common dictionary definition of process is "a series of actions or
operations definitely conducting to an end." Obviously
process is associated with all forms of social behavior.
Political scientists traditionally have been interested in institutional processed,
that is, those "series of actions or operations" associated with legislatures,
executives, bureaucracies, courts, political parties, and other political institutions. Many, if not most, political science courses focus
on these processes: what they are, how they work, what they produce, and how they connect. Generalizations are developed about such
processes as budget making, administrative rule making, congressional voting, priority
setting, making appointments, reorganization, and committee decision making. More often than not, these generalizations cut
across substantive issues. [16]
Focusing on group processes is also popular. In
this approach it is assumed that groups are absolutely crucial in political decision
making. One studies the role of interest
groups but also looks for groups within political institutions. The latter groups may not always coincide with the
organizational framework of the institution. [17]
The focus here is on public problems and how they are acted on in government. It is assumed that problems themselves help to
shape the structure and organization of government, and that often cross-institutional and
intergovernmental connections will emerge to treat these problems. Generalizations are
developed about issues or issue areas as well as the activities associated with resolving
them.[18]
3.2. Conceptual Approaches to Study the
Methodology of Policy Process
There are several conceptual process approaches to study policy making processes. They differ in terms of the focus of analysis and
the nature of the generalizations. Examples
of the more frequently used approaches are: a)
focus on real social powers and institutions; b) formal elected officials as primary axis
of representations; c) dynamics of different and relevant groups of pressure; d)
historical social conditions and trend of political needs; and e) the external and
internal political and economic conditions as social domestic factors. [19]
None of them is one more legitimate than the others; rather, each contributes to a
fuller understanding of the others. Each is
an effort to describe and analyze reality: for example, committees as institutional groups
are real; interactions among outside formal groups are real; public problems are very
real. Finally, each emphasis may reveal an
aspect of the political or decision-making system that is obscured by the others.
These conceptual approaches need to deal with the concrete conditions in which a
particular policy making process is carried out. For
example, they must take into account who participates and interacts with whom in a
particular matter. It may well be, for
example, that not all members of a congressional committee participate in exploring
solutions to a problem, whereas lobbyists, bureaucrats, and private consultants do. The student of group processes attempts to
identify this cross-institutional participation and generalize about its nature. Various elite theories propose that decisions are
actually make by small groups that may or may not communicate with their publics. In this view the group process is really an elite
process. [20]
Some people are primarily interested in the substance of issues; that is, in the
nature of the problems and how they can be solved. For
example, they want to understand the essential elements of inflation, unemployment, or
trade imbalances in order to identify alternative courses of action for solving these
problems. Their expertise is related to these
substantive issues, for example, as labor, economic, education, or trade specialists.
Many political scientists are more interested in process than substance. For them
substance (e.g. inflation and actions to curb it) is merely a way to study process. Their expertise develops out of knowledge about
the organization, routines, and decisions of government and other public agencies. [21]
3.3. Defining Policy
Those studying the policy process do not have the advantage of a common reference. A definition is required to determine what to look
for in "policy". The definition I
favor is offered by Heinz Eulau and Kenneth Prewitt:
"Policy is defined as a "standing decision" characterized by
behavioral consistency and repetitiveness on the part of both those who make it and those
who abide by it. [22]
This definition leaves us with the problems of determining how long a decision must
stand, what constitutes behavioral consistency and repetitiveness, and who actually
constitutes the population of policy makers and policy abiders, but it does identify some
of the components of public policy.
Here then are two broad uses of the term policy: one as a word substitute or
shorthand where common understanding is assumed; another as a set of characteristics to be
specified and then identified through research. Clearly the second is more applicable to
the present objective. For the purpose here
is to encourage study of public policy and how it is made.
We do not plan to conduct research on policy questions as such. The plan is rather to provide a basis for
understanding the "behavioral consistency and repetitiveness" associated with
efforts in and through government to resolve public problems. Used in this way, policy is a highly dynamic term.
As Eulau and Prewitt point out, "What the observer sees when he identifies
policy at any one point in time is at most a stage or phase in a sequence of events that
constitute policy development."[23] To put it another way, we
freeze the action for purposes of analysis. Whatever
we learn must be specified in terms of the questions we seek to answer, the time frame
within which our research is conducted, and the institutional units being studied.
Therefore any reference to "defense policy," "farm policy," or
"social security policy" should lead us to ask, What do you mean by that? Are
you speaking of national goals? Current statutes? Recent decisions? Or are you
characterizing certain behavioral consistencies by decision makers? The point of asking
these questions is not to enforce one particular definition of the term policy, but rather
to clarify meanings and thereby improve understanding.
One important observation is that, Eulau and Prewitt also observe that "policy
is distinguished from policy goals, policy intentions, and policy choices."[24] What this suggests is that it is helpful to
distinguish the several components of public policy.
For example:
a) Intentions: The true purposes of an
action
b) Goals: The stated ends to be
achieved
c) Plans or proposals: Specified means for achieving the goals
d) Programs: Authorized means for achieving goals
e) Decisions or choices: Specific actions taken to set goals, develop plans,
implement and evaluate programs.
f) Effects: The measurable impacts of programs (intended and unintended; primary and secondary)
One can reasonably use the term policy as an adjective with each of these
components, but it does become somewhat confusing if the term is used interchangeably with
all of them. We should also note the more
legal terms associated with public policy making: legislation, laws, statutes, executive
orders, regulations, legal opinions. these
too are often called policy. For our
purposes, however, they are simply the formal ingredients or legal expressions of programs
and decisions. [25]
3.4.
A Policy Process Framework
The following table shows a synthesis of the main activities and particular
questions often confronted in the policy making process, at its different levels of
decisions.
Table 2:
Activities and Questions for Public
Policy Analysis
Activities |
Questions |
Perception / definition |
What is the problem related
with the proposal? |
Aggregation |
How many people think it is
an important problem? |
Organization |
How well organized and power
have these people? |
Representation |
What is the access to
decision makers? |
Agenda setting |
How and how establishes the
agenda topics? |
Formulation |
What is the proposed
solution? |
Legitimation |
Who supports the main
decisions? Any groups of power? |
Budgeting |
What is the financial
condition? |
Implementation |
Who administers the budget? |
Evaluation |
Who judges the achievements
and based on what criteria? |
Adjustment / termination |
What adjustments have been
made and what adjustments it is possible to predict? |
Source: Jones, Ch. Ob.Cit.
p. 27-28; Dunn, W. Public Policy Analysis. (New Jersey: Prentice Hall, 1994). p. 15-19.
The policy activities listed can be grouped in sequence of government action. The first five are associated with getting the
problem to government and the next three with direct action by the government to develop
and fund a program. Implementation is really
the government returning to the problem, and the last two activities (evaluation and
adjustment/termination) can be thought of as returning the program to government (for
review and possible change).
Each activity may also be thought of as yielding a product that often contributes
to the next activity. For example,
perception and definition can result in a clearly specified problem; formulation in a
definite proposal or plan.
3.5. Theoretical Approaches to Study the
Policy Making Process and the Political Foundations of Main Actors
Participants vary in how they view the policy process and in what they seek to gain
from it. At a minimum we can identify
rationalists, technicians, incrementalists, and reformists.
All four types of actors will typically be involved in any complex issue. However, at any one time or for any one issue,
one or more of the groups may dominate. The
four types of participants vary in the roles they play in the policy process, the values
they seek to promote, the source of goals for each, and their operating styles. [26]
3.5.1. Rationalists
"The main characteristic of rationalists is that they involve reasoned choices
about the desirability of adopting different courses of action to resolve public
problems."[27] This process of reasoned
choice 1) identifies the problem, 2) defines and ranks goals, 3) identifies all policy
alternatives, 4) forecasts consequences of each alternative, 5) compares consequences in
relationship with goals, and 6) chooses the best alternative.[28] This approach is associated with the role of the
planner and professional policy analyst, whose training stresses rational methods in
treating public problems.
Often the methods themselves are valued by the rationalist and therefore are
promoted. It is assumed that goals are
discoverable in advance and that "perfect information" is available.[29] The operating style tends to be that of the
comprehensive planner; that is, one who seeks to analyze all aspects of the issue and test
all possible alternatives by their effects and contribution to the stated goals. Most readers probably find this approach
appealing. It strikes one as commonsensical
to be as comprehensive as possible. Unfortunately,
both institutional and political characteristics frequently interfere with the realization
of so-called rational goals.
3.5.2. Technicians
A technician is really a type of rationalist, one engaged in the specialized work
associated with the several stages of decision making. Technicians may well have
discretion, but only within a limited sphere. They
normally work on projects that require their expertise but are defined by others. The role they play is that of the specialist of
expert called in for a particular assignment. The
values they promote are those associated with their professional training, for example, as
engineers, physicists, immunologists, or statisticians.
Goals are typically set by others, perhaps any of the other three types identified
here (or a mix of them). the operating style
of the technician tends to be abstracted from that on the rationalist (who tends to be
comprehensive). The technician displays
confidence within the limits of training and experience but considerable discomfort if
called upon to make more extensive judgments. [30]
3.5.3. Incrementalists
Charles Jones associates incrementalism with politicians in our policy system.
Politicians tend to be critical of or impatient with planners and technicians, though,
dependent on what they produce. Incrementalists
doubt that comprehensiveness and rationality are possible in this most imperfect world.
They see policy development and implementation as a "serial process of constant
adjustment to the outcomes (proximate and long-range) of action."[31]
For incrementalists, information and knowledge are never sufficient to produce a
complete policy program. They tend to be
satisfied with increments, with building on the base, with working at the margins. The values associated with this approach are those
of the past or of the status quo. Policy for
incrementalists tends to be a gradual unfolding. Goals
emerge as a consequence of demands, either for doing something new or, more typically, for
making adjustments in what is already on the books. Finally,
the operating style of incrementalists is that of the bargainer-constantly hearing
demands, testing intensities, and proposing compromises. [32]
3.5.4. Reformists
Reformists are like incrementalists in accepting the limits of available
information and knowledge in the policy process, but are quite different in the
conclusions they draw. Incrementalists judge
that these limits dictate great caution in making policy moves. As David Braybrooke and Charles Lindblom note,
"Only those policies are considered whose known or expected consequences differ
incrementally from the status quo."[33]
This approach is much too conservative for reformists who, by nature, want to see
social change. They would agree with David
Easton that "we need to accept the validity of addressing ourselves directly to the
problems of the day to obtain quick, short-run answers with the tools and generalizations
currently available, however inadequate they may be."[34] The emphasis is on acting now because of the
urgency of problems. This is the approach
taken by self-styled citizen lobbyists. The
values are those related to social change, sometimes for its own sake but more often
associated with the special interests of particular groups.
Goals are set within the group by various processes, including the personal belief
that the present outcomes of government action are just plain wrong. The operating style of reformists has become very
activist, often involving demonstrations and confrontation.
Given the striking differences among these four types of participants it is not
surprising that each group in highly critical of the others. It is alleged, for example, that rationalists
simply do not understand human nature. Braybrooke
and Lindblom state that the rationalist's "ideal is not adapted to man's limited
problem-solving capacities."[35] Technicians are criticized for their narrowness. Incrementalists rely too much on the status quo
and fail to evaluate their own decisions. Reformists are indicted for their unrealistic
demands and uncompromising nature.
Different eras do appear to evoke different perspectives: the incrementalism of the 1950s, the reformism of
the 1960s and 1970s, the rationalism of the late 1970s and the early 1980s (particularly
in energy, environmental, and economic planning). But
in every era our politics is characterized by a mix of participants within and among the
institutions. Thus each group is forced at some point to deal with or encounter the
others. The product may favor one perspective at a given stage of the policy process, but
the multiplicity of institutions, governments, and decision making insures a melding over
time.
Table 3:
Four Perspectives in Public Policy
Analysis
Perspective |
Characteristics Roles
Values
Goals
Style
|
Criticism |
|||
Rationalist |
Policy
Analyst/Planner |
Method |
Discover |
Comprehensive |
Failure to acknowledge limits |
Technician |
Expert
/ Specialist |
Training
/ Expertise |
Set
by others |
Explicit |
Narrowness |
Incrementalist |
Politician |
Status
quo |
Set
by new demands |
Bargaining |
Conservative |
Reformist |
Citizen
/ Lobbyist |
Change |
Set
by substantive concerns |
Activist |
Unrealistic, Uncompromise. |
Source: Jones, Ch.
Ob.Cit. p. 32.
4.
Principal Models for Public Policy Analysis
4.1. General Considerations
The core decision in economics is "What do we want and what can we get?.
Ordinarily we want more than we can get, and because our capabilities are limited and the
resources available to us scarce, choices must be made among our competing desires. The Port Authority would like to expand airport
operations and at the same time reduce noise levels.
It cannot do both; as headlines testify, the choice is difficult. How choices should be made-the whole problem of
allocating scarce resources among competing ends-is the stuff of economics and the subject
of this book. [36]
In public policy analysis we focus on choices in the public sector, on how
decisions should be made by governments at all levels and by nonprofit institutions. As we are by now all well aware, the government is
not a business, and in many respects it cannot be run like a business. Its goals are different and it operates under
different constraints. Yet the basic elements of good decisions are the same in all
arenas, and the methods for making them set forth here are applicable for all decision
makers, public and private.
Our starting point is a fundamental model of choice.
We have seen that a model is a simplified representation of some aspect of the real
world, a deliberate distillation of reality to extract the essential features of a
situation. The fundamental choice model is particularly valuable because it offers a
universal yet succinct way of looking at problems in terms of the two primary elements of
any act of choice: [37]
1. The alternatives available to the decision maker; and
2. His preferences among these alternatives.
The model forces the decision maker to express the alternatives he faces and his
preferences among them in comparable units. You
will see from our examples that the alternatives may sometimes be described in tangible
terms, actual outputs that can be seen and counted, such as electricity and water, or
allergy tests and electrocardiograms. At
other times the outputs of the alternative choices will be described in terms of
intangible attributes such as intelligence and beauty, or taste and nutrition, or safety
and speed. Some of these intangibles can be
measured more or less objectively; others cannot. The
model is flexible; it easily handles all types of attributes, whether described by hard
numbers or paragraphs of prose, so long as the decision maker's preferences are expressed
in the same terms as the alternatives.[38]
In terms of alternatives available to the decision maker, the first element of the
basic model describes the alternatives available to the decision maker. If this were a standard economics text, we would
introduce you to apples and oranges and ask you to consider the plight of the grocery
shopper who must allocate his fruit budget between those two goods. But this is a document about public decisions, so
we ask you instead to play the part of a public official who must choose among several
alternative dam projects. These projects are
identical in every respect-costs, environmental consequences, and so on-except two: they
produce different amounts of electric power and water for irrigation. In other words, the decision maker faces a certain
number of alternative quantities of power and water. [39]
A main general concept about public policy analysis is the marginal analysis tool. This concept includes the discussion of marginal
rates of transformation and substitution is only one example of the type of analysis that
forms the core of traditional microeconomics theory.
In a nutshell, in order to achieve an optimal result, the allocation of scarce
resources among competing uses must satisfy certain marginal equalities. For example, the consumer should allocate his
budget so that he gets the same satisfaction from the last dollar he spends on orange
juice and the last dollar he spends on going to the ballet.
And a rational consumer will do just that, even though he will rarely do so
consciously. A farmer or the manager of a
pencil factory should expand production just to the point where his last dollar of sales
costs him exactly $1. Producing more
diminishes his profit, producing less means that he forgoes some of the profit he might
have reaped. Similarly, a public decision
maker-a mayor, for example should allocate spending on park maintenance and on fire
protection so that the last dollar spent on each is equally satisfying to the society he
represents. [40]
The model of choice to develop public policy analysis requires that preferences be
expressed in the same units as the outcomes of the various alternatives proposed. Thus, if the decision maker is offered a choice
among assorted combinations of apples and oranges, his preferences must be expressed also
in terms of apples and oranges. Conversely,
if he is to choose a mix of strange fruit whose attributes are a mystery to him, although
he knows his preferences for, say, vitamins and juiciness, the outcomes of the various
possible choices must be expressed not as bundles of fruit but as combinations of these
attributes. In other words, he must be able
to measure these fruits in terms of the characteristics he understands, cares about, and
can work with.[41]
The following sections will address discussions concerning the most frequently
models used to carry out public policy analysis.
4.2.
Difference Equations
This method is more useful when the features of the phenomenon under study are
quantitative variables. Difference equations
have the significant advantage to allow us to take into account the dynamic change in the
variables, and thus the possibility to identify possible trends of the variables.
4.2.1.
A General Description and Illustrations
There are two ways we can represent dynamic processes. We can view things as changing continuously over
time, which is in fact generally the case, or we can break in on a process or system at
specified time intervals and see where things are.
Difference equations take the period-by-period or discrete approach: they relate
the value of a variable in a given time period to its values in periods past. They are an essential feature of the financial
world; indeed the compound interest model that we used is a simple difference equation:
S1
= (1 + r ) So
Here S1, the sum of money in a savings bank account at the end of a year, is
related to the initial sum So; r is the rate of interest.
For example, this equation is valid whether r is 5 percent, 7 percent, or 100
percent. Note the use of subscripts, numbers
or letters written to the right of and a little below the symbol for the variable, to
indicate the specific time at which a variable is being valued. They are typical of difference equations: using
the variables So and S1 rather than completely different symbols such as A and B for the
variables serves to remind us that we are talking about a particular chunk of money, even
though the exact sum in question is different at different times. [42]
Listed below are a few illustrations of the many sorts of situations in which
difference equation models are useful:
1. A couple wishes to set
aside money to supplement Social Security when they retire in twenty years. They want to know what their savings will be when
they retire if they invest $2000 per year at 7 percent interest, and how long those
savings will last if after retirement they withdraw $5000 per year, continuing to earn 7
percent on the balance left in their account.
2. A school district has overcrowded classrooms. There is pressure to relieve this overcrowding,
either by building a new school or by renting temporary facilities. In order to decide between these two alternatives,
the school board needs projections of the school-age population in the district over the
next two decades.
3. The president of a university is concerned about
its ability to fund ongoing programs. He
needs projections of income and expenses over the next 10 years to help him decide what
policies to follow with respect to tuition, scholarship aid, and faculty hiring.
4. A state department of public health is
considering a new program to detect and treat hypertensives. It has guesstimates of how many new hypertensives
would be discovered every month, what proportion would then enter treatment, and what the
attrition rate from the program would be. In
order to put together a budget, the department needs estimates of the number of people in
treatment during the first two years of the program.
5. The 1970 Clear Air Act mandates stepped reduction
in the permissible level of pollutants emitted by new cars. The possibility of requiring the owners of older
cars to add pollution control devices has been discussed. Given the rates at which older
cars go out of service, how much difference would such a policy make in the total amount
of auto emissions?
6. A mosquito control district is considering
several alternative spraying programs, all of which have the same dollar cost. It needs a model of mosquito reproduction and of
the effects of different spraying programs in order to determine the most effective plan. [43]
An extremely important aspect of difference equations is the choice of the
appropriate time interval-the amount of time that elapses between time 0 and time 1-to use
in a difference equation depends on the particular problem at hand. If we were examining the growth of a flu epidemic,
for instance, days or weeks might be appropriate, whereas for the growth of world
population we would be more likely to look at years or decades.[44]
4.2.2. The General Form of a Difference
Equation
Thus far our difference equations have modeled changes for specific periods of
time, an initial period (0) and one period later (1).
Usually we are more interested in a general statement that relates the value of the
variable in any time period to its value in the preceding period. In the compound interest model, it would be useful
to have an expression for Sn, the sum at the nth period, in terms of what S was in period
(n-1). This of course offers greater
flexibility in applying the formula. In this
case it is clear what that formula must be; we simply write:
Sn
= (1 + r ) Sn-1
For all n ³ 1
Where Sn-1 is the sum on deposit at the end of the (n-1) period. This equation is called the general form of the
difference equation, because it holds in general and not just for specific values of n. It is a first-order difference equation because
the variable Sn can be determined from its value in the one preceding period only. [45]
4.2.3. Difference Equations of Higher
Order
Consider the following statement:
The Bonex Company prefers, earnings permitting, to pay dividends according to the
following rule: The dividend on a share of
common stock should be equal to 90 percent of last year's dividend plus one and one-half
times the previous year's change in dividend.
This exercise is designed to illustrate a situation slightly more complicated than
those previously encountered. Here we are
concerned with a dividend, D, that depends on its value not only in the last period but
also in the period before last. The general
difference equation is:
This is presented only as an example, the difference equations in this case is of
higher order, since the value of n must be equal or higher than 2.[46]
4.2.4. The Use of Difference Equations
in Modeling
Ordinarily we expect to see difference equations used as sub models, to predict
parts of a system rather than the system as a whole.
This is not to downgrade the importance of difference equations. Indeed, few people would view predictions about
the future availability of oil as unimportant. In
constructing their models, policy analysts rely on the existing age structure and
predictions as to the future behavior of variables such as age-specific birth rates, death
rates, migration rates, percent of the population gainfully employed, retirement age, wage
rates, and the like, with difference equations playing a central role.
In this part we have discussed the use of difference equations primarily as a
vehicle for introducing a variety of concepts and techniques. We must keep in mind that our main goal in
developing these models is better predictions of the outcomes of policy alternatives.[47]
4.3.
Queuing or Ranking Method
4.3.1. General Features
Problems of public policy analysis in which it is possible to apply queuing or
ranking methods, are characterized by the fact that a service facility is too limited to
provide instantaneous service to all of its customers on all occasions. We do not want that people wait for services, but
on the other hand, installing additional service capacity is too expensive. Queuing problems arise whenever a service facility
is too limited to provide instantaneous service to all of its customers on all occasions. When the customers arrive more swiftly than they
can be serviced, lines or queues will develop.
Waiting is costly; frequently we would pay to avoid it.
It is, of course, impossible to eliminate waiting altogether; the costs would be
prohibitive. A fire engine for every house in
a rural area would protect against the one in a trillion possibility that all the engines
will be needed at the same time, but it would obviously be undesirable. This is a straightforward matter of tradeoffs: the
shorter we wish waiting time to be, the more facilities we must have available. To be more specific, the model can tell us
how the waiting time for service will respond to the level of facilities that is made
available. How much, for example, can the
local Social Security office shorten clients' waiting times by opening another window?
Occasionally it is also possible to change the time required for service; what would be
the result of improving procedures so as to cut service time by two minutes?[48]
Studying the way queues behave is important for public policy because the
relationship between waiting times and service capacity is far from obvious, while the
cost of providing extra capacity is likely to be large.
Even simple models can help us grasp the essence of a great variety of real-world
situations, and the results are often surprising.
4.3.2.
Probabilistic Queuing Models
When customers arrive for service at a regular and predictable rate, as we assumed
they did at the toll bridge, long lines may develop as a result of sheer numbers; expected
arrivals may exceed the service capacity. A
deterministic model that pays no attention to uncertainties can then predict directly the
effects of adding or subtracting stations. Most
queuing problems are not so tractable; customers
usually arrive at irregular rates. Take the
case of a facility that can serve up to 12 people per hour if they arrive at regular
intervals. One day 3 people may arrive during
the first hour and 18 during the next hour. As
a result, people must queue up even when there is, on average, enough service capacity. In other words, a facility may be able on paper to
serve a given number of customers per day provided they arrive regularly. But if they arrive irregularly, as a practical
matter the facility will serve far fewer than its theoretical capacity. As the average number demanding service each day
rises, waiting times will become intolerable.
In the real world, queuing systems are of course likely to be much more complex and
to involve several different kinds of random events.
In principle the problem is still likely to be straightforward, although
programming the computer may become more of a chore.
It's useful to keep in mind a checklist of the types of random events and
complications that can occur in a queuing system. These
fall under three main aspects:[49]
1. Arrivals. Arrival
intervals may be independent of one another, or the fact of one arrival may influence the
probability as to when the next occurs. The
latter will true whenever customers are likely to arrive in groups, as at an airport
customs station. The arrivals in the Registry
of Motor Vehicles example were independent, on the assumption that a driver's license
expires on the holder's birthday. In
contrast, 20 percent of the hypertension clinic patients arrived in groups of two or more,
reflecting the greater likelihood that people would choose to make joint trips to the
facility. It is also possible that the arrival pattern might vary with the time of day, or
with the number of people waiting for service.[50] So
if we wished to make the model more sophisticated, we could relate patient arrival
frequencies to the number of patients waiting. We
might, for example, use one frequency distribution when fewer than 5 people are waiting,
another when 5 to 10 are waiting, and so on. In
this way we would recognize the influence of service characteristics on arrival behavior. It's more work to program the computer for the
fancier model, but conceptually the problem is no more
difficult.
2. Service times.
Different people may require different service times. Further, the service time for
on person may be affected by the number waiting of by the nature of the services rendered
those who preceded him. Again, such variations on the basic model make the programming
more burdensome, and it would be necessary to develop data on the frequency distribution
for service times. But no fundamental changes
in the model are required.
3. The "queue discipline." The way in which the queue forms and moves may
not be a straightforward one right after the other straight line process. There may be more than one line; line jumping may
be permitted; perhaps people who receive service must then get in another queue for a
second service. With the hypertension
clinic's lunch breaks, we introduced the possibility of a variable number of service
stations. There may be bumping or other
priority procedures.
Note that changes in the quality of service will show up as changes in queuing
behavior only if arrival or service times of the queue discipline are affected. Service quality as such need not appear
independently in the model.
4.4. Simulation and Non-Lineal Methods
4.4.1. General Features
The policy arena, the true world of affairs, is not always compatible to the
straightforward use of analytic methods. The
analyst may be confronted with problems that are too intricate to solve directly. He can write down equations that describe the
workings of a system, and this may be a useful discipline in itself. But given the complex interactions within the
system, even modern mathematical techniques are not powerful enough to predict the
consequences of any policy choice.
In such a case, we can try to construct a laboratory model of the system. The model can be physical; frequently ship or
plane designs are tested on scale models in water tanks or wind tunnels. It may be highly abstract; military strategies are sometimes tested by
reproducing battlefield conditions on what is essentially a game board. If alternative predictions are made as to how
individual encounters between elements of the opposing forces will be resolved, the board
representation enables army strategists to consider the overall outcome of many
simultaneous encounters. [51]
Models of this sort are also helpful to transportation planners who must predict
traffic flows, say to determine the benefits of a new bypass. Behavioral equations are employed to predict , for
instance, how motorists' decisions will respond to traffic density-how they will change
the timing of their trips, or the routes, or the destinations. A simulation method thus attempts to
reproduce a system in what is the equivalent of a laboratory setting, in many occasions we
need to conclude using concepts of chaos theory in order to represent the main factors,
the more important limitations concerning the phenomenon under study, and the more
probable trends of results.
Sometimes we wish to examine the histories that may result from alternative policy
choices. For example, suppose a number of
different pollutants are discharged into a river at several places along it. A model can be constructed to relate water
conditions at various points downstream to the levels of these discharges. This model of the river basin could then be used
for studying the effects of regulatory discharge levels.
Any number of policy choices in the form of possible combinations of discharge
levels may be investigated, and their performance assessed.
At other times we wish to investigate the implications of changes in certain key
parameters. A river, for example, has an
extraordinary ability to cleanse itself-provided pollution does not exceed certain levels. Even though it is polluted over an upstream
stretch, the river may be relatively free of pollution at its mouth. Perhaps the volume of municipal sewage discharges
is critical for this regenerative capacity. [52]
Simulations directed to random situations, such as those usually encountered in
queuing problems, generally run through a great number of histories to provide a feel for
the frequency distribution of outcomes.
4.4.2. Macroeconomic Simulation
In the last quarter century, simulations
of national economies and of the world economy have come into increasing prominence. These models use large numbers of data to predict
the behavior of key variables in the economy-investment, consumption, employment, imports
and exports, government expenditures, and the like-over the next few quarters or years. A typical model might relate consumption in year
t, for example, to wages and profits in the same year, and investment in year t to profits
in years t and (t-1). Government
economists trying to determine the optimal level of government spending and corporate
planners trying to determine the optimal level of investment rely on them. To a degree, the models build in an element of
self-fulfillment as decision makers respond to their predictions. Similar macroeconomic models are now used to try
to predict future world use of certain vital resources, especially oil. [53]
4.4.3.
Simulation as an Analytic Tool
Analysts recognize that there are many problems in formulating informative
simulations and usually employ them only as a last resort.
The difficulties encountered in building the model can be formidable; frequently
independent verification of the accuracy of the model is impossible. In addition, probabilistic output, the usual
output of a simulation, is susceptible to misuse, particularly if some of the information
is not presented.
For example, suppose the average epidemic for a population of 100 people turns out
to be 5 cases. This average could have
resulted from epidemic sizes of 4, 7, 3, 5, 6, and so on, year after year. Or it could conceivably conceal the fact that no
epidemic occurs 19 years out of 20, but then everyone is laid low at once; the average
epidemic is still 5 cases. Obviously this
information could be misleading; as a precaution, the analyst should insist on seeing a
sampling of complete runs as well as the final averages.
Despite these risks, in many situations informative simulation is the appropriate
recourse for the analyst. Used wisely, it is an indispensable tool for predicting the
outcomes of alternative policies.[54]
4.5. Markov Chains
Simple models sometimes yield compelling conclusions. Such models are worthy of study if their basic
elements reappear in a variety of situations. Markov models are among these models; an
understanding of them yields insights into a number of policy issues. Pollutants moving through the biosphere, mentally
ill individuals moving from one level of functional capability to another, heroin users
moving from addiction to treatment to abstention and back again-all can be illuminated by
casting them in a Markov framework.
Consider the following situation, [55] which we will describe with the aid of a
Markov model. New Kent has a labor force of
10,000 people. In any month, each of these
10,000 people is either employed (E) or unemployed (U).
At present, 3000 are unemployed. As
things now stand, 90 percent of those employed in one y ear are still employed the
following year, while 40 percent of the unemployed find jobs and are employed in the next
year. These proportions hold true year after
year. New Kent's employment situation is
summarized in the following table or matrix. This
type of matrix is called a transition matrix because it describes how changes take place
from one period to another.
Next period
E
U
E
.90
.10
This period
U .40
.60
E = employed
U = unemployed
The first row of numbers tells us what proportion of the people who are employed in
the first period will still be employed in the next, and what proportion will be
unemployed. Thus the .90 in row E, column E.
means that of the people who are employed in the first period, .90 or 90 percent will be
employed in the next period. The second row
gives us the same information about those who are unemployed in the first period. We might also have labeled the two periods
"y" and "y+1," since it is stipulated that the proportions don't
change from year to year.
We could have used a set of difference equations to set forth the information
contained in the transition matrix:
E2 = .90E1 + .40U1
U2 = .10E1 + .60U1
The main advantage of the matrix notation is its simplicity, in writing and
especially in manipulation. This becomes much
more important as the number of different categories increases.
The situation we have just examined is an example of a Markov system. In this case
we have considered movements within an entire population, New Kent's labor force, from
employed or unemployed in one period to employed or unemployed in the next period. When we observe the probabilistic movements of a
single individual, the process is called a Markov chain.
The arithmetic for the two situation is identical.[56]
4.5.1.
Markov Chains: An Example
Let's consider an individual-we'll call him Smith-who is either well (W) or sick
(S). Moreover, if Smith is well one day, he
has an 80 percent chance of being well the next day.
If he is sick, he has a 50 percent chance of being well the next day. These probabilities depend only on his condition
today, an assumption that is crucial; his previous history doesn't matter. Smith's health
is completely described by the following transition matrix, which defines a Markov chain:
Period 2
W
S
W .80
.20
Period 1
S
.50
.50
Customarily we assign a
label, let us call it P, to this matrix and write it simply as
.8 .2
P=
.5 .5
These probabilities for the state of Smith's health hold for any two consecutive
periods.[57]
4.5.2. Main Properties of a Transition
Matrix
The main properties of a transition matrix that define a finite Markov chain,
taking into account the aforementioned example are:
First, there must be a finite number of well-defined categories or states, such
that the individual falls in one and only one state in each period; the mathematician's phrase is mutually exclusive
and collectively exhaustive. This means that the system is closed-the individual always
stays within it and does not move to some state outside the system, which is equivalent to
stating that the numbers in each row of the matrix must add up to 1. Sometimes this inclusiveness requirement may be
satisfied by enlarging the matrix, in other words by adding states so that all
possibilities are accounted for. For example,
suppose Smith, when he is well, has an 80 percent chance of remaining well and a 15
percent chance or being sick in the following period.
He also has a 5 percent chance of dying and hence moving out of the two-state
system. We may keep him in the system by
adding "dead" as a third state.
A second property is that the probabilities in the transition matrix must be the
same for any tow consecutive periods.
A third property is the so-called Markov condition: the probabilities must have no
memory. It doesn't matter whether Smith was
well or sick yesterday; the probability of his being well tomorrow depends only on how he
is today. Suppose you find that the
probability of his being well tomorrow, given that he is sick today, depends on how long
he has been sick, and not just on whether he's well or sick in this period. Perhaps that probability is 50 percent if he has
been sick one day, but only 30 percent if he has been sick longer. At first glance this presents insurmountable
difficulties, but if only a few periods of history matter we can cope with the situation. In this particular set of circumstances, we
replace the state "sick" with two states, "sick for one day" (S1) and
"sick for two days or longer" (S2). The
matrix Q would then represent a Markov chain:
Period 2
W S1 S2
W .80 .20 0
Period 1
S1 .50 0 .50 = Q
S2 .30 0 .70
W = well
S1 = sick for one day
S2 = sick for two days or longer
If the number of states that the chain "remembers" is finite, it is
possible to satisfy the Markov requirement by redefining the states in this manner.
A fourth property of a Markov chain is that time periods must be uniform in length. This may seem to be a superfluous requirement , as
here they are automatically defined that way. But
now and then it can give trouble. Generations,
for example, are a very difficult time unit to work with.
Moreover, with longer periods we have to pay attention to moves out of and back
into a state within a single period. If these
conditions-inclusive states, constant and memory-less probabilities, and uniform period
lengths-are satisfied, then we have a Markov chain.[58]
4.5.3.
Regular, Absorbing, and Cyclical Chains
With regular Markov chains we may draw two conclusions about the long-run
probabilities: (1) for the long run, the probability of being in a particular state
approaches an equilibrium value that is independent of the state that the individual is in
initially; (2) these equilibrium probabilities may be interpreted as the percent of time
spent in each state over the very long run.
With absorbing chains, the equilibrium is frequently uninteresting. We are more likely to want to know how many
periods an individual can be expected to spend in each state before he is absorbed, or how
quickly he is likely to get trapped. If there
is more than one absorbing state, we may be interested in knowing what the probability is
that the individual lands in each.
The fully cyclical chains tell us no more than what is intuitively obvious. The rotation continues perpetually, and where you
are at any particular time depends on where you started and how many periods have passed. with a partially cyclical chain, the individual
will become trapped in the rotation eventually, but if we know where he started, we will
at least be able to estimate the expected number of periods that will pass before he is
caught up in the rotation.
Finally, it is important to specify how the long run is in term of Markov chains.
The answer is, "It all depends." If
there is very little movement between states and if there are a large number of states,
the system will be slow to converge toward its equilibrium probabilities. For example, consider the following well-sick
transition matrix:
Period 2
W
S
W .99999 .00001
Period 1
S
.00003 .99997
W = well
S =
sick
The equilibrium probabilities for this system are .75 and .25 for well and sick. But this is scant comfort for a sick man, whose
chances of getting well quickly are slim. Contrast
this with our earlier well-sick matrix, where the long-run probabilities weren't quite as
favorable (.714 and .286), but which converged to the equilibrium probabilities much more
rapidly. If there are a large number of
states, rather than just two, and period length is , say, one week, the system may take
years to come close to equilibrium.[59]
4.6. Cost-Benefit Method
4.6.1. Cost-Benefit Analysis and Project
Evaluations
4.6.2.
The Procedure
1. The project or projects to
be analyzed are identified.
2. All the impacts, both
favorable and unfavorable, present and future, on all of society are determined.
3. Values, usually in
dollars, are assigned to these impacts. Favorable
impacts will be registered as benefits, unfavorable ones as costs.
4. The net benefit (total
benefit minus total cost) is calculated.
5. The choice is made. Criteria for making this decision are discussed in
a later section of
this chapter.
The
formal rules for benefit-cost analysis use as inputs estimates of the benefits and costs
of the projects. But a knowledge of these
rules is only the beginning of wisdom for the decision maker. He must confront such matters as:
1. Deciding which rule is appropriate for use in any particular circumstance;
2. Placing a complex problem in a benefit-cost framework;
3. Computing estimates of benefits and costs; and
4. Deciding at what level of detail and sophistication an analysis should be
conducted.
4.7.
Linear Programming
4.7.1. The Elements of a Linear
Programming Problem
Anyone
who understands linear programming can readily comprehend the basic ideas behind the more
complicated types of mathematical programming. Our assumptions of constant returns,
divisibility, and additivity are purely for expository reasons; none is critical for the
kind of use that we wish to make of mathematical programming.
Political, economic, social, and institutional constraints usually place direct
limits on levels at which the activities may be used.
For example, in the diet problem we might wish to achieve a taste balance as well
as a nutritional balance. A typical set of
budget constraints for an institution might require that no program receive less than last
year, nor more than a 10 percent increase over last year.
Or it might specify that the ratio of the amounts expended on two programs remain
within certain limits. In all these cases we
are, in a sense, establishing subsidiary objectives for certain activities.
4.7.2.
The Limitations of Linear Programming
First, some of the relationships may be nonlinear, and some of the variables may
take only integral values.[64]
Second, the constraints are such that no feasible solution
yields acceptable score on the objective function. In
that case, one possibility is merely too do the best we can with the onerous set of
constraints. Alternatively, we can go back
and see if the original problem can be re specified.
Perhaps when the lack of acceptability of outcomes is pointed out to the
individuals or agencies that imposed the constraints.
5.
Public Policy Analysis: A General Methodology to Apply
5.1.
Establishing the Context
Considering
the context and in social and economic terms, the range of possible explanations for
unsatisfactory market performance are:
1. Information is not shared costlessly among all prospective participants in the market.
2. Transactions costs
significantly impede the conduct of beneficial trades.
3. The relevant markets do
not exist.
4. Some of the participants
in the market exercise market power.
5. Externalities are present,
so that the actions of one individual (whether a person or an organization) affect the
welfare of another.
6. The commodity involved in
the policy choice is a public good.
Under any of these conditions, or if a compelling distributional objective will be
served, government intervention may be appropriate. A
policy analysis is then merited. [66]
5.2.
Determining Alternatives
With the context of the problem clearly in mind, we can proceed to the second step:
What are the alternative courses of action? The
alternatives for policy choice are often much broader than they first seem. Government intervention can take many forms; in
any particular situation it is important to determine which type is most appropriate.
Can
the alternative courses of action be designed so as to take advantage of additional
information as it becomes available? A
flexible decision process will enable the decision maker to change his course of action as
he learns more about the real world in which he must operate. [67]
5.3. Establishing the Consequences
Once the problem is well-defined and the alternative courses of action delineated,
the policy analyst must try to predict what will happen.
What are the consequences of each of the alternative actions? Occasionally, mere reflection will be sufficient
to trace the course from actions to outcomes. In
some situations, the model will serve as little more than an intellectual guide.
5.4. Valuing the Outcomes
Some
valuation problems, particularly those that involve intangibles, do not lend themselves to
quantification. In such a case, analysis can
address the issue descriptively. Perhaps a
proposed welfare program is perceived as damaging the dignity of the recipients; that fact
should be included in the analysis as one output of the program, just as the total dollar
cost would be. Identifying the key intangibles is as much a part of the analyst's job. In any case, values must be assigned openly and
explicitly.
Recognizing that an alternative will inevitably be superior with respect to certain
objectives and inferior with respect to others, how should different combinations of
valued objectives be compared with one another? Assigning
values to specific attributes is only a small part of the difficulty in defining
preferences. In almost every serious policy
choice, painful tradeoffs must be made among valued attributes. [68]
5.5.
Determining a Choice
The
choice among competing policy alternatives in never easy, for the future is always
uncertain and the inescapable tradeoffs painful. The
methods set forth here cannot eliminate these difficulties, but they can help us manage
them. By improving our ability to predict the
consequences of alternative policies, and providing a framework for valuing those
consequences, the techniques of policy analysis lead us toward better decisions.[69]
Pittsburgh, July 2001
6. Bibliography
Aguilar, M. Tratado de Economia. (Mexico: Aguilar Eds., 1987).
Braybrooke, D. A Strategy of Decision. (New York: Free Press, 1983).
Correa, H. Multivariate Analysis. (Pittsburgh: GSPIA,
1994).
Dewey, J.
The Public and Its Problems. (New
York: Holt and Winston Publish., 1987).
Dunn, W. Publlic
Policy Analysis. (New Jersey:
Prentice Hall, 1994).
Etzioni, A. The
Active Society. (New York: Free Press, 1989).
Eulau, H; Prewitt, K. Labyrinths
of Democracy. (Indianapolis: Merrill,
1989).
Frohok, M.
Public Policy, Scope and Logic. (New Jersey:
Prentice Hall, 1979).
Greenberger, M. Models in Policy Process. (New York: Russell Found., 1986).
Hochman, H. Redestribution
through Public Choice. (New York: Columbia Univ. Press, 1976).
Jones, Ch.
The Study of Public Policy. (Monterrey: Brooks,
1990).
Lasswell, H. A
Preview of Policy Sciences. ( New
York: Elsevier, 1992).
Nagel, S.
Enclycopedia of Policy Studies. (New York: Marcel
Dekker, 1991).
Ochaeta R. Procesos
de Politica Publlica. (Guatemala: INAP, 1993).
Olson, M.
The Logic of Collective Action. (Cambridge: Harvard
University Press, 1991).
Orellana, E. Introduccion y Aplicaciones de la Teoria de Caos.
(Mexico: LIMUSA, 1989).
Raymond A.
Study of Policy Formation. (New York: Free
Press, 1992).
Raymond, A. Public
Policy Process. (New York: Free Press, 1988).
Rothenberg, J. The Measurement of Social Welfare. (New
Jersey: Prentice-Hall, 1982).
Russell L. Ackoff and Maurice W. Sasieni, Fundamentals of Operations Research (New
York:Wiley, 1968).
Samayoa A. Aplicaciones del Analisis de Costo-Beneficio.
(Guatemala, USAC, 1987).
Samuelson, P. Economics. (Boston: MIT,
1993).
Schultze, Ch. The Public Use of Private Interest. (Washington, D.C.: The Brookings Institution,
1992).
Smith, D. Pragmatism
and the Group Theory of Politics. (New
York: BCB, 1988).
Stokey, E. A
Primer for Public Policy. (London: Norton, 1991).
Tobin, J. Introduccion a las Ecuaciones Diferenciales.
(Bogota: McGraw-Hill, 1990).
Torres-Rivas Edelberto. Interpretacion
del Desarrollo Social Centroamericano. (San Jose: EDUCA,
1988).
Truman, D.
The Govermental Process (New York: Knopf, 1992).
Weber, M. Economia
y Sociedad. (Mexico: Fondo de Cultura Economica, 1991)
Wright, M. The Power Elite. (New York: Oxford University Press, 1989)
[1] See Weber, M. Economia
y Sociedad. (Mexico: Fondo de Cultura Economica, 1991). p. 12-34.
[2] See Torres-Rivas Edelberto. Interpretacion
del Desarrollo Social Centroamericano. (San Jose: EDUCA, 1988).
p. 35-42.
[3] Raymond A. Study of
Policy Formation. (New York: Free Press, 1992).
p. 15-23.
[4] Ibid.
p. 25.
[5] Dewey, J. The
Public and Its Problems. (New York: Holt
and Winston Publish., 1987) p. 17.
[6] Smith,
D. Pragmatism
and the Group Theory of Politics. (New
York: BCB, 1988). p. 32.
[7] Samuelson,
P. Economics. (Boston: MIT,
1993), p. 23-25; 45-53.
[8] Hochman, H. Redestribution
through Public Choice. (New York: Columbia University Press, 1976). p. 34-36.
[9] Ibid. p. 44.
[10] Stokey, E. A
Primer for Public Policy. (London: Norton, 1991).
p. 12.
[11] Jones, Ch.
The Study of Public Policy. (Monterrey: Brooks,
1990). p.17-19
[12] Ibid. p. 21
[13] Ibid. p. 43.
[14] Nagel, S.
Enclycopedia of Policy Studies. (New York: Marcel
Dekker, 1991) . p. 55.
[15] Jones, Ch.
Ob.Cit. p. 54.
[16] Lasswell, H. A Preview
of Policy Sciences. ( New York: Elsevier, 1992), p. 54-58.
[17] Truman, D.
The Govermental Process (New York: Knopf, 1992), p. 66.
[18] Ibid.
[19] Ochaeta R. Procesos
de Politica Publlica. (Guatemala: Instituto Nacional de Administracion Publica,
1993),
p. 45-48.
[20] Wright, M.
The Power Elite. (New York: Oxford
University Press, 1989)
[21] Ochaeta R.
Ob. Cit. p. 71
[22] Eulau, H; Prewitt, K. Labyrinths
of Democracy. (Indianapolis: Merrill,
1989). p. 41.
[23] Ibid.
[24] Ibid. p. 473.
[25] Stokey, E. Ob. Cit. 11.
[26] Jones, Ch.
Ob. Cit. p. 30-33.
[27] Dunn, W. Publlic Policy Analysis. (New Jersey: Prentice Hall, 1994). p. 226.
[28] Ibid.
[29] Frohok, M. Public
Policy, Scope and Logic. (New Jersey: Prentice Hall, 1979). p. 45.
[30]Jones, Ch. Ob.Cit. p. 30-31.
[31]Ibid. p. 31.
[32] Etzioni, A. The
Active Society. (New York: Free Press, 1989).
Chapter 12.
[33]Braybrooke, D. A Strategy of Decision. (New York: Free Press, 1983). p. 77-85
[34]Ibid.
[35]Ibid. p. 87.
[36] See Raymond, B. The
Study of Policy Formation. (New York: Free Press, 1988).
[37]
Stokey, E. Ob. Cit. p. 26-28.
[38] Ibid. p. 31.
[39] Olson, M. The Logic of Collective Action. (Cambridge: Harvard
University Press, 1991). p.55.
[40] Stokey E. Ob. Cit. p. 36.
[41] Ibid.p.38.
[42] Correa, H. Multivariate
Analysis. (Pittsburgh: GSPIA, 1994). p. 18-23.
[43] Stokey, E. Ob.Cit.p. 48-49.
[44] Ibid. p. 50.
[45] Schultze, Ch. The Public Use of Private Interest. (Washington, D.C.: The Brookings Institution,
1992). p.33.
[46] Ibid. p. 42.
[47] Tobin, J. Introduccion
a las Ecuaciones Diferenciales. (Bogota: McGraw-Hill, 1990). p. 23-34.
[48] Stankey, E. Ob.Cit. p. 76.
[49] Ibid. 80-81.
[50] See for example, Russell L. Ackoff and Maurice W.
Sasieni, Fundamentals of Operations Research (New
York:Wiley, 1968).
[51] Orellana, E. Introduccion y Aplicaciones de la Teoria de Caos.
(Mexico: LIMUSA, 1989). p.18-24.
[52] Ibid. p. 33.
[53] Aguilar, M. Tratado de Economia. (Mexico: Aguilar Eds., 1987).p.57.
[54] Stokey, E. Ob.Cit.p.97.
[55] Ibid.p.98.
[56] Ibid.
[57] Ibid. p. 101.
[58] Ibid.p. 104-105; Orellana, E.
Ob.Cit. p. 65.; and Tobin, J. Ob.Cit.p.88.
[59]
Stakey, E. Ob.Cit. p.107.
[60] Greenberger, M. Models in Policy Process. (New York: Russell Found., 1986).
[61]
Stakey, E. Ob. Cit. p.156.
[62] Samayoa A. Aplicaciones del Analisis de Costo-Beneficio.
(Guatemala, USAC, 1987).p.43-47
[63] Stakey, E. Ob.Cit. p.154.
[64]Ibid. p. 156.
[65] Jones, Ch. Ob.Cit. p. 233-238;
Stakey, E. Ob.Cit. p.321.
[66] Jones, Ch. Ob.Cit. p. 239.
[67] Stakey, Ob.Cit. p.324.
[68] Ibid, p. 325.; and Rothenberg, J.
The Measurement of Social Welfare. (New
Jersey: Prentice-Hall, 1982).p.56.
[69] Stakey, Ob.Cit. p.327-329.
Return to Sincronía Summer 2001
Return to Sincronía General Index