Four Main Theories of Development:
Giovanni E. Reyes
Graduate School of Public and International Affairs -GSPIA-
Contents
1. Introduction
2. Theory of modernization
3.Theory of dependency
4.Theory
of world-systems
5.Theory of globalization
6. Bibliography
1. Introduction
The main objective of this document is to synthesize the main aspects of the four
major theories of development: modernization,
dependency, world-systems and globalization. These
are the principal theoretical explanations to interpret development efforts carried out
especially in the developing countries. These
theoretical perspectives allow us not only to clarify concepts, to set them in economic
and social perspectives, but also to identify recommendations in terms of social policies.
For the purposes of this paper, the term development is understood as a social
condition within a nation, in which the authentic needs of its population are satisfied by
the rational and sustainable use of natural resources and systems. This utilization of natural resources is based on
a technology, which respects the cultural features of the population of a given country. This general definition of development includes
the specification that social groups have access to organizations, basic services such as
education, housing, health services, and nutrition, and above all else, that their
cultures and traditions are respected within the social framework of a particular country.
In economic terms, the aforementioned definition indicates that for the population
of a country, there are employment opportunities, satisfaction -at least- of basic needs,
and the achievement of a positive rate of distribution and redistribution of national
wealth. In a political sense this definition
emphasizes that governmental systems have legitimacy not only in terms of the law, but
also in terms of providing social benefits for the majority of the population.[1]
2. Theory of Modernization
According to Alvin So, there are three main and historical elements which were
favorable to the inception of the modernization theory of development after the Second
World War. First, there was the rise of the
United States as a superpower. While other
Western nations, such as Great Britain, France, and Germany, were weakened by World War
II, the United States emerged from the war strengthened, and became a world leader with
the implementation of the Marshall Plan to reconstruct war-torn Western Europe.[2]
Second, there was the spread of a united world communist movement. The Former Soviet Union extended its influence not
only to Eastern Europe, but also to China and Korea.
Third, there was the disintegration of European
colonial empires in Asia, Africa and Latin America, giving birth to many new nation-states
in the Third World. These nascent
nation-states were in search of a model of development to promote their economy and to
enhance their political independence.[3]
According to the modernization theory, modern societies are more productive,
children are better educated, and the needy receive more welfare. According to Smelsers analysis, modern
societies have the particular feature of social structural differentiation, that is to say
a clear definition of functions and political roles from national institutions. Smelser argues that although structural
differentiation has increased the functional capacity of modern organizations, it has also
created the problem of integration, and of coordinating the activities of the various new
institutions.[4]
In a political sense, Coleman stresses three main features of modern societies: a) Differentiation of political structure; b)
Secularization of political culture -with the ethos of equality-, which c) Enhances the
capacity of a societys political system.[5]
The major assumptions of the modernization theory of development basically are: Modernization is a phased process; for example
Rostow has 5 phases according to his theory of economic development for a particular
society, and I will mention them later. Modernization
is a homogenizing process, in this sense, we can say that modernization produces
tendencies toward convergence among societies, for example, Levy (1967, p. 207) maintains
that : as time goes on, they and we
will increasingly resemble one another because the patterns of modernization are such that
the more highly modernized societies become, the more they resemble one another.[6]
Modernization is a europeanization or americanization process; in the modernization
literature, there is an attitude of complacency toward Western Europe and the United
States. These nations are viewed as having
unmatched economic prosperity and democratic stability (Tipps: 1976, 14). In addition, modernization is an irreversible process, once
started modernization cannot be stopped. In
other words, once third world countries come into contact with the West, they will not be
able to resist the impetus toward modernization.[7]
Modernization is a progressive process which in the long run is not only inevitable
but desirable. According to Coleman,
modernized political systems have a higher capacity to deal with the function of national
identity, legitimacy, penetration, participation, and distribution than traditional
political systems. Finally, modernization is
a lengthy process. It is an evolutionary
change, not a revolutionary one. It will take
generations or even centuries to complete, and its profound impact will be felt only
through time. All these assumptions are
derived from European and American evolutionary theory. [8]
There is also another set of classical
assumptions based more strictly on the functionalism-structuralism theory which emphasizes
the interdependence of social institutions, the importance of structural variables at the
cultural level, and the built in process of change through homeostasis equilibrium. These are ideas derived especially from
Parsons sociological theories.[9]
These assumptions are as follows: a) Modernization is a systematic process. The attribute of modernity forms a consistent
whole, thus appearing in a cluster rather than in isolation; [10]
b) Modernization is a transformative process;
in order for a society to move into modernity its traditional structures and values must
be totally replaced by a set of modern values;[11] and c) Modernization is an imminent process due to its
systematic and transformative nature, which builds change into the social system.
One of the principal applications of the modernization theory has been the economic
field related to public policy decisions. From
this perspective, it is very well known that the economic theory of modernization is based
on the five stages of development from Rostows model.
In summary, these five stages are: traditional
society, precondition for takeoff, the takeoff process, the drive to maturity, and high
mass consumption society. According to this
exposition, Rostow has found a possible solution for the promotion of Third World
modernization. If the problem facing Third
World countries resides in their lack of productive investments, then the solution lies in
the provision of aid to these countries in the form of capital, technology, and expertise. The Marshall Plan and the Alliance for Progress in
Latin America, are examples of programs which were influenced by Rostows political
theories.[12]
The strengths of modernization theory can be defined in several aspects. First, we can identify the basis of the research
focus. Despite the fact that the main studies
of modernization were carried out by a psychologist, a social psychologist, a sociologist
of religion and a political sociologist, other authors have extended modernization theory
into other spheres. For example, Bellah
examines the role of the Tokugawas religion on pajanes economic development in South-East
Asia with effects on villages of Cambodia, Laos and Burma;
Lipset addresses the possible role of economic development in the democratization
of Third World countries, and Inkeles discusses the consequences of the modernization
process for individual attitudes and behavior. [13]
A second feature of the modernization perspective is the analytical framework. Authors assume that Third World countries are
traditional and that Western countries are modern. In order to develop, those poor nations
need to adopt Western values. In third place,
the methodology is based on general studies; for
example the expositions regarding the value factors in the Third World, and the
differentiation between unstable democracies, dictatorships and stable dictatorships.
Modernization theory, on the other hand, was
popular in the 1950s, but was under heavy attack at the end of the 60s. Criticisms of the theory include the following: First, development is not necessarily
unidirectional. This is an example of the
ethnocentricity of Rostows perspective. Second,
the modernization perspective only shows one possible model of development. The favored example is the development pattern in
the United States. Nevertheless, in contrast
with this circumstance, we can see that there have been development advances in other
nations, such as Taiwan and South Korea; and we must admit that their current development
levels have been achieved by strong authoritarian regimes.[14]
A second set of critiques of the modernization theory regards the need to eliminate
traditional values. Third World countries do
not have an homogeneous set of traditional values; their value systems are highly
heterogeneous. For example Redfield 1965,
distinguishes between the great traditional values (values of the elites), and the little
tradition (values of the masses).[15] A second aspect for
criticism here is the fact that traditional and modern values are not necessarily always
mutually exclusive: China, for example,
despite advances in economic development continues to operate on traditional values and
this appears to be the same situation in Japan. Moreover,
it is not possible to say that traditional values are always dichotomous from modern
status, for example, loyalty to the Emperor can be transformed to loyalty to the firm.
The similarities between classical modernization studies and new modernization
studies can be observed in the constancy of the research focus on Third World development;
the analysis at a national level; the use of three main variables: internal factors, cultural values and social
institutions; the key concepts of tradition and modernity; and the policy implications of modernization in the sense that it is considered
to be generally beneficial to society as a whole.
However, there are also important distinctions between the classical studies and
the new studies of the modernization school. For
example, in the classical approach, tradition is an obstacle to development; in the new approach, tradition is an additive
factor of development. With
regard to methodology, the classical approach applies a theoretical construction with a
high-level of abstraction; the new approach applies concrete case studies given in an
historical context. Regarding the direction
of development, the classical perspective uses an unidirectional path which tends toward
the United States and European model, the new perspective prefers a multidirectional path
of development. And finally, concerning
external factors and conflict, the classicals demonstrate a
relative neglect of external factors and conflict, in contrast to the greater
attention to external factors and conflicts practiced by the new approach. [16]
3.
Theory of Dependency
The foundations of the theory of dependency emerged in the 1950s from the research
of the Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean -ECLAC-. One of the most representative authors was Raul
Prebisch. The principal points of the
Prebisch model are that in order to create conditions of development within a country, it
is necessary:
a) To control the monetary exchange
rate, placing more governmental emphasis on fiscal rather than monetary policy;
b) To promote a more effective
governmental role in terms of national development;
c) To create a platform of
investments, giving a preferential role to national capitals;
d) To allow the entrance of external capital following priorities already
established in national plans for development;
e) To promote a more effective
internal demand in terms of domestic markets as a base to reinforce the industrialization
process in Latin America;
f) To generate a larger internal demand by increasing the wages and salaries of
workers, which will in turn positively affect aggregate demand in internal markets;
g) To develop a more effective coverage of social services from the government,
especially to impoverished sectors in order to create conditions for those sectors to
become more competitive; and
h) To develop national strategies according to the model of import substitution,
protecting national production by establishing quotas and tariffs on external markets. [17]
The Prebisch and ECLACs proposal were the basis for dependency theory at the
beginning of the 1950s.[18] However, there are also several authors, such as
Falleto and Dos Santos who argue that the ECLACs development proposals failed, which
only then lead to the establishment of the
dependency model. This more elaborated
theoretical model was published at the end of the 1950s and the mid 1960s. Among the main
authors of dependency theory we have: Andre
Gunder Frank, Raul Prebisch, Theotonio Dos Santos, Enrique Cardozo, Edelberto
Torres-Rivas, and Samir Amin.[19]
The theory of dependency combines elements from a neo-marxist perspective with
Keynes economic theory - the liberal economic ideas which emerged in the United
States and Europe as a response to the depression years of the 1920s-. From the Keynes economic approach, the
theory of dependency embodies four main points: a) To develop an important internal effective demand
in terms of domestic markets; b) To recognize
that the industrial sector is crucial to achieving better levels of national development,
especially due to the fact that this sector, in comparison with the agricultural sector,
can contribute more value-added to products; c) To increase workers income as a means of
generating more aggregate demand in national market conditions; d) To
promote a more effective government role in order to reinforce national development
conditions and to increase national standards of living.[20]
According to Foster-Carter (1973), there are three main differences between the
classic orthodox Marxist movement and the neo-marxist positions, the latter providing a
basis for the dependency theory. First, the
classical approach focuses on the role of extended monopolies at the global level, and the
neo-marxist on providing a vision from peripheral conditions. Second, the classical movement foresaw the need
for a bourgeois revolution at the introduction of national transformation processes; from
the neo-marxist position and based on current conditions of Third World countries, it is
imperative to jump to a socialist revolution, mainly because it is perceived
that national bourgeoisies identify more strongly with elite positions rather than with
nationalistic ones. Third, the classical
Marxist approach perceived the industrial proletariat as having the strength and vanguard
for social revolution; the neo-marxist approach emphasized that the revolutionary class
must be conformed by peasants in order to carry out an armed revolutionary conflict.[21]
Although the modernization school and the dependency school conflict in many areas,
they also have certain similarities, the most important being: a) A
research focus on Third World development circumstances; b)
A methodology which has a high-level of abstraction and is focused on the
development process, using nations-state as a unit of analysis; c) The use of polar theoretical structural visions;
in one case the structure is tradition versus modernity -modernization-, in the other it
is core versus periphery -dependency-. [22]
The major hypotheses with regard to development in Third World countries according
to the dependency school are the following: First,
in contrast to the development of the core nations which is self-contained, the
development of nations in the Third World necessitates subordination to the core. Examples of this situation can be seen in Latin
America, especially in those countries with a high degree of industrialization, such as
Sao Paulo, Brazil which Andre G. Frank uses as a case study.
Second, the peripheral nations experience their greatest economic development when
their ties to the core are weakest. An
example of this circumstance is the industrialization process that took root in Latin
America during the 1930s, when the core nations were focusing on solving the problems that
resulted from the Great Depression, and the Western powers were involved in the Second
World War.[23]
A third hypothesis indicates that when the core recovers from its crisis and
reestablishes trade and investments ties, it fully incorporates the peripheral nations
once again into the system, and the growth of industrialization
in these regions is stifled. Frank in
particular indicates that when core countries recuperate from war or other crises which
have directed their attention away from the periphery, this negatively affects the balance
of payments, inflation and political stability in Third World countries. Lastly, the fourth aspect refers to the fact that
regions that are highly underdeveloped and still operate on a traditional, feudal system
are those that in the past had the closest ties to core.[24]
However, according to Theotonio Dos Santos, the basis of dependency in
underdeveloped nations is derived from industrial technological production, rather than
from financial ties to monopolies from the core nations.
In addition to Dos Santos, other classical authors in the dependency school are: Baran, who has studied conditions in India in the
late 1950s; and Landsberg, who has studied
the processes of industrial production in the core countries in 1987.[25]
The principal critics of the dependency theory have focused on the fact that this
school does not provide exhaustive empirical evidence to support its conclusions. Furthermore, this theoretical position uses highly
abstract levels of analysis. Another point of
critique is that the dependency movement considers ties with transnational corporations as
being only detrimental to countries, when actually these links can be used as a means of
transference of technology. In this sense, it
is important to remember that the United States was also a colony, and this country had
the capacity to break the vicious cycle of underdevelopment.[26]
The new studies of dependency theory are due to the work of Enrique Cardozo (1979),
and Falleto (1980). These authors take into
account the relations that exist in a country in terms of its systemic -external-, and its
sub-systemic -internal- level, and how these relationships can be transformed into
positive elements for the development of peripheral nations. ODonell studied the case of relative
autonomy between economic and political elements within conditions of Third World
countries, especially those in South East Asia. Evans
studied the comparative advantage that Brazil has with its neighbors in South America, and
Gold studied the dependency elements which were operating at the beginning of the process
by which Taiwan constituted itself in a country.[27]
A predominant point of the new dependency studies is that while the orthodox
dependency position does not accept the relative autonomy of government from the powerful
elites, the new authors of this school perceive a margin of movement of national
governments in terms of pursuing their own agenda. These
arguments originated mainly from the writings of Nikos Poulantzas. For this political scientist, governments in Third
World countries have a certain amount of autonomy from the real axis of power within the
nation.[28]
One of the main current critiques of the theory of dependency and the theory of
modernization is that they both continue to base their assumptions and results on the
nation-state. This is an important point
that allows us to separate these aforementioned schools from the theoretical perspective
of world-systems or globalization theory. These
last movements have focused their attention mostly on the international connections among
countries, especially those related to trade, the international financial system, world
technology and military cooperation.
4. Theory of World Systems
A central element from which the theory of world-systems emerged was the different
form that capitalism was taking around the world, especially since the decade of the
1960s. Starting in this decade, Third World
countries had new conditions in which to attempt to elevate their standards of living and
improve social conditions. These new
conditions were related to the fact that the international financial and trade systems
began to have a more flexible character, in which national government actions were having
less and less influence. Basically
these new international economic circumstances made it possible for a group of radical
researchers led by Immanuel Wallerstein to conclude that there were new activities in the
capitalist world-economy which could not be explained within the confines of the
dependency perspective. These new features
were characterized mainly by the following aspects:
a) East Asia (Japan, Taiwan, South
Korea, Hong Kong, and Singapore) continued to experience a remarkable rate of economic
growth. It became more and more difficult to
portray this East Asian economic miracle as
manufacturing imperialism;
b) There was a widespread crisis among
the socialist states which included the Sino-Soviet split, the failure of the Cultural
Revolution, economic stagnation in the socialist states, and the gradual opening of the
socialist states to capitalist investment. This
crisis signaled the decline of revolutionary Marxism;
c) There was a crisis in North
American capitalism which included the Vietnam War, the Watergate crisis, the oil embargo
of 1975, the combination of stagnation and inflation in the late 1970s, as well as the
rising sentiment of protectionism, the unprecedented governmental deficit, and the
widening of the trade gap in the 1980s, all signaling the demise of American hegemony in
the capitalist world-economy.[29]
These elements created the conditions for the emergence of the world-systems
theory. This school had its genesis at the
Fernand Braudel Center for the Study of Economics, Historical Systems, and Civilization at
the State University of New York at Binghamton. Having
originated in sociology, the world-systems school has now extended its impact to
anthropology, history , political science, and urban planning. I. Wallerstein is
considered one of the most important thinkers in this theoretical field. At the beginning of his career he studied the
development problems that the recently independent African nations needed to face taking
into account the new capitalist economic and political conditions of the world in the
1960s.[30]
Wallerstein and his followers recognized that there are worldwide conditions that
operate as determinant forces especially for small and underdeveloped nations, and that
the nation-state level of analysis is no longer the only useful category for studying
development conditions, particularly in Third World countries. Those factors which had the greatest impact on the
internal development of small countries were the new global systems of communications, the
new world trade mechanisms, the international financial system, and the transference of
knowledge and military links. These factors
have created their own dynamic at the international level, and at the same time, these
elements are interacting with the internal aspects of each country.[31]
The main assumptions of the world-systems theory establish that: a) There
is a strong link between social sciences - especially among sociology, economics and
political disciplines. This school recognizes that more attention is usually given to the
individual development of each one of these disciplines rather than to the interaction
among them and how these interactions affect in real terms the national conditions of a
given society; b) Instead of addressing the analysis
of each of the variables, it is necessary to study the reality of social systems; c) It is necessary to recognize the new character of
the capitalist system. For example, the approach followed by the classical political
economy perspective is based on the conditions of the capitalist system during the
industrial revolution in the United Kingdom. There
was concrete evidence to support open competition, more productive patterns in the
industrial sector, and wide groups of population which provided labor for the new
established factories.[32]
Today this is not the situation especially when we consider the important economic
role of transnational corporations, the international political climate, the
interdependence that affects the governments of poor nations, and the role of speculative
investments. For the world-systems school,
present economic conditions are not fully explainable within traditional development
theories. This criticism of the capitalist
system has been present since its birth. Under
current international conditions, there are specific features of monopoly capital, its
means of transaction, and its concrete operations worldwide which have affected
international relations among nations to a considerable degree.
The principal differences between the world-systems approach and the dependency
studies are: a) The unit of analysis in the
dependency theory is the nation-state level, for the world-system it is the world itself; b) Concerning methodology, the dependency
school posits that the structural-historical model is that of the boom and bust of nation
states, the world systems approach maintains the historical dynamics of world-systems in
its cyclical rhythms and secular trends; c) The theoretical structure for the dependency
theory is bimodal, consisting of the core and
the periphery; according to the world systems
theory the structure is trimodal and is comprised of the core, the semiperiphery and the
periphery; d) In terms of the direction of development, the dependency school believes
that the process is generally harmful; however, in a world systems scenario, there is the
possibility for upward and downward mobility in the world economy; e) The research focus of dependency theorists
concentrates on the periphery; while world systems theorists focus on the periphery as
well as on the core, the semiperiphery and the periphery.[33]
Given the aforementioned characteristics, the world-systems theory indicates that
the main unit of analysis is the social system, which can be studied at the internal level
of a country, and also from the external environment of a particular nation. In this last case the social system affects
several nations and usually also an entire region.
The world systems most frequently studied in this theoretical perspective are
systems concerning the research, application and transference of productive and basic
technology; the financial mechanisms, and world trade operations. In terms of financial resources, this development
position distinguishes between productive and speculative investments. Productive investments are financial resources
which reinforce the manufacturing production in a particular nation, while speculative
investments normally entail fast profits in the stock market, they do not provide a
country with a sustainable basis for long term economic growth, and therefore are more
volatile.
When the world-systems theory considers trade mechanisms, it distinguishes between
the direct transactions, which are those who have a greater, more significant and
immediate effect on a country; and those operations which are indirect trade transactions,
such as future trade stipulations, and the speculations on transportation costs,
combustibles prices, and forecasts on agricultural crops, when they depend on weather
conditions to obtain their productivity and yield.[34]
5. Theory
of Globalization
The theory of globalization emerges from the global mechanisms of greater
integration with particular emphasis on the sphere of economic transactions. In this sense, this perspective is similar to the
world-systems approach. However, one of the
most important characteristics of the globalization position is its focus and emphasis on
cultural aspects and their communication worldwide. Rather
than the economic, financial and political ties, globalization scholars argue that the
main modern elements for development interpretation are the cultural links among nations. In this cultural communication, one of the most
important factors is the increasing flexibility of technology to connect people around the
world.[35]
The main aspects of the theory of globalization can be delineated as follows:
a) To recognize that global
communications systems are gaining an increasing importance every day, and through this
process all nations are interacting much more frequently and easily, not only at the
governmental level, but also within the citizenry;
b) Even though the main communications
systems are operating among the more developed nations, these mechanisms are also
spreading in their use to less developed nations. This
fact will increase the possibility that marginal groups in poor nations can communicate
and interact within a global context using the new technology;
c) The modern communications system
implies structural and important modifications in the social, economic and cultural
patterns of nations. In terms of the economic
activities the new technological advances in communications are becoming more accessible
to local and small business. This situation
is creating a completely new environment for carrying out economic transactions, utilizing
productive resources, equipment, trading products, and taking advantage of the
virtual monetary mechanisms. From
a cultural perspective, the new communication products are unifying patterns of
communications around the world, at least in terms of economic transactions under the
current conditions;
d) The concept of minorities within
particular nations is being affected by these new patterns of communications. Even though these minorities are not completely
integrated into the new world systems of communications, the powerful business and
political elites in each country are a part of this interaction around the world Ultimately, the business and political elite
continue to be the decision makers in developing nations;
e) Cultural elements will dictate the
forms of economic and social structure in each country.
These social conditions are a result of the dominant cultural factors within the
conditions of each nation.[36]
The main assumptions which can be extracted from the theory of globalization can be
summarized in three principal points. First,
cultural factors are the determinant aspect in every society. Second, it is not important, under current world
conditions to use the nation-state as the unit of analysis, since global communications
and international ties are making this category less useful. Third, with more standardization in technological
advances, more and more social sectors will be able to connect themselves with other
groups around the world. This situation will
involve the dominant and non-dominant groups from each nation.
The theory of globalization coincides with several elements from the theory of
modernization. One aspect is that both
theories consider that the main direction of development should be that which was
undertaken by the United States and Europe. These
schools sustain that the main patterns of communication and the tools to achieve better
standards of living originated in those more developed areas. On this point it is important to underline the
difference between the modernization perspective and the globalization approach. The former follows a more normative position
-stating how the development issue should be solved-, the latter reinforces its character
as a positive perspective, rather than a normative claim.[37]
Another point in which the modernization and the globalization theories coincide is
in terms of their ethnocentric point of view. Both
positions stress the fact that the path toward development is generated and must be
followed in terms of the US and European models. Globalization
scholars argue that this circumstance is a fact in terms of the influence derived from the
communications web and the cultural spread of values from more developed countries.
Globalization theories emphasize cultural factors as the main determinants which
affect the economic, social and political conditions of nations, which is similar to the
comprehensive social school of Max Webers theories. From this perspective, the systems of values,
believes, and the pattern of identity of dominant -or hegemony- and the alternative -or
subordinate- groups within a society are the most important elements to explain national
characteristics in economic and social terms.[38] It is obvious that for the globalization position
this statement from 1920s Weberian theory
must apply to current world conditions especially in terms of the diffusion and transference of cultural values
through communication systems, and they are increasingly affecting many social groups in
all nations.
Based on the aforementioned elements it is clear that the globalization and
world-systems theories take a global perspective in determining the unit of analysis,
rather than focusing strictly on the nation-state as was the case in the modernization and
dependency schools. The contrasting point
between world-systems theory and globalization, is that the first contains certain
neo-marxist elements, while the second bases its theoretical foundations on the structural
and functionalist sociological movement. Therefore
the globalization approach tends more toward
a gradual transition rather than a violent or revolutionary transformation. For the globalists authors, the gradual changes in
societies become a reality when different social groups adapt themselves to current
innovations, particularly in the areas of cultural communication.[39]
The globalization and world-systems theories take into account the most recent
economic changes in world structure and relations that have occurred in the last couple of
decades, for example: a) In March 1973, the governments of the more
developed nations, began to operate more flexible mechanisms in terms of exchange rate
control. This situation allowed for a faster
movement of capital among the worlds financial centers, international banks, and
stock markets; b) Since 1976 trade
transactions base their speculations on the future value of the products, which is
reinforced through the more flexible use of modern technology in information, computers,
and in communication systems; c) The computer revolution of the eighties made it
possible to carry out faster calculations and transactions regarding exchange rates values
and investments, which was reinforced by the general use of the fax machine; d) During the
nineties the main challenge is from the Internet which allows the achievement of more
rapid and expansive communication. The
Internet is increasingly creating the conditions to reinvigorate the character of the virtual economy in several
specific markets.
Under the current conditions, the main aspects that are being studied from the
globalization perspective are: a) New concepts, definitions and empirical evidence
for hypotheses concerning cultural variables and their change at the national, regional
and global level; b) Specific ways to adapt the principles of comprehensive sociology to the
current global village atmosphere; c) Interactions
among the different levels of power from nation to nation, and from particular social
systems which are operating around the world; d) How new patterns of communications are affecting
the minorities within each society; e) The
concept of autonomy of state in the face of increasingly flexible communication tools and
international economic ties, which are rendering obsolete the previous unilateral
effectiveness of national economic decisions; and f)
How regionalism and multilateralism agreements are affecting global economic and
social integration.
6. Bibliography
Adam, J. Foreign Policy in Transition. (Chapel Hill, North Caroline: University of North Caroline Press,1992).
Aguilera, G. Dialectica del Terror en Guatemala. (San Jose, Costa Rica: EDUCA, 1989).
Akzin, B. Estado y Nacion. (Mexico: Fondo de Cultura Economica, 1988).
Alexander, R. Financiamiento Externo, Deuda y Transformacion Productiva. (San Salvador, El Salvador: UCLA, 1990).
Alford, R. Los Poderes de la Teoria. Capitalismo, estado y democracia. (Buenos Aires, Argentina:Editorial Manantial, 1991).
Arias, S. Centro America: Obstaculos y Perspectivas del Desarrollo. (San Jose, Costa Rica: DEI,1993).
Arnson, C. Contadora and the Diplomacy of Peace in Central America. (Boulder, Colorado: Westview Press, 1990).
Banco de Guatemala. Memoria de Labores y Estudio Economico. (Guatemala: Banco de Guatemala, 1994).
Bell, D. El Advenimiento de la Sociedad Post-Industrial. (Madrid: Ed. Alianza, 1987).
Bergesen, A. Long Waves of Colonial Expansion and Contraction in Studies of the Modern World-System. (New York: Academic Press, 1984).
Bodenheimer, S. Dependency and Imperialism: The roots of Latin American underdevelopment. (New York: NACLA, 1970).
Bulmer-Thomas, V. Politica Economica en Centroamerica desde 1920. (Mexico: Trillas, 1993).
Bulmer-Thomas, V. Studies in the Economics of Central America. (London: MacMillan Press, 1992).
Cardoso, F. and Falleto, E. Dependency and Development in Latin America. (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1979).
Chirot, D. Social Change in a Peripheral Society: The creation of a Balkan colony. (New York:Academic Press, 1993).
Coatsworth, J. Central America and the United States. (New York: Twayne Publishers, 1994).
Codas, R. Introduccion al Estudio de la Cooperacion Internacional en Centroamerica. (San Salvador,El Salvador: PREIS, 1991).
Comision Economica para America Latina y el Caribe. Transformacion Productiva con Equidad. (Santiago, Chile: CEPAL, 1991).
Diaz, A. Introduccion al Mercado Comun Centroamericano. (Madrid: ICEX, 1992).
Diaz-Bonilla, E. Structural Adjustment Programs and Economic Stabilization in Central America.(Washington, D.C.: The World Bank, 1990).
Dos Santos, T. The Structure of Dependence. (Boston: Extending Horizons, 1971).
Etzioni. E. Social Change. (New York: Basic Books, 1991).
Facultad Latinoamericana de Ciencias Sociales e Instituto Interamericano de Cooperacion para la Agricultura. Centro America en Cifras 1994. (San Jose, Costa Rica: IICA, 1995).
Fagen, R. Theories of Development: The question of class strugle. Monthly Review 35, 1983, 13-24.
Fisher, S. Macroeconomics (New York: MacMillan, 1994).
Foster-Carter, A. Neo-Marxist Approaches to Development and Underdevelopment. Journal of Contemporary Asia 3, 1973, 7-33.
Frank, G. Capitalism and Underdevelopment in Latin America. (New York: Monthly Review Press, 1967).
Frank, G. Latin America: Underdevelopment and Revolution. (New York: Monthly Review Press, 1969).
Friedrichs, R. A Sociology of Sociology. (New York: Free Press, 1970).
Galbraith, J. La Cultura de la Satisfaccion. (Buenos Aires: Ariel, 1992).
Garcia, D. Estado y Sociedad: La nueva relacion a partir del cambio estructural (Buenos Aires, Argentina: FLACSO, 1994).
Goldfrank, W. The World-System of Capitalism: Past, and Present. (Beverlly Hills, California: SAGE,1986).
Gough, I. Economia Politica del Estado de Bienestar. (Madrid, España: Blume, 1992).
Habermas, G. Crisis of Legitimacy (New York: MacMillan, 1992).
Habermas, G. Theory of Social Communication. (New York: MacMillan, 1992).
Hailstones, T. Viewpoints on Supply-Side Economics. (Reston, Virginia: Reston Publs., 1984).
Held, D. Modelos de Democracia. (Madrid, España: Alianza Editorial, 1992).
Hermassi, E. Changing Patterns in Research on the Third World, Annual Review of Sociology 4, 1978,239-257.
Herrera, V. Centroamerica en Cifras 1980-1992. (San Jose, Costa Rica: FLACSO, 1995).
Hirschman, A. De la Economia a la Politica y Mas alla. (Mexico: Fondo de Cultura Economica, 1987).
Hirst, P. Social Evolution and Sociological Categories. (London: Allen Publs. 1986).
Huntington, S. The Change to Change: Modernization, development and politics. (New York: Free Press, 1976).
Irving, G. Central America: The Future of Economic Integration. (Boulder, Colorado: Westview Press,1989).
Isuani, E. El Estado Benefactor. Un Paradigma en Crisis. (Buenos Aries, Argentina: Miño y Davila,1991).
Kaplan, B. Social Change in the Capitalist World. (Beverly Hills, California: SAGE, 1993).
Killing, J. The Quest for Economic Stabilization: The IMF and the Third World. (London: Overseas Development Institute, 1984).
Keith, N. New Perspectives on Social Class and Socioeconomic Development in the Periphery. (New York: Greenwood Press, 1990).
Kissinger, H. Report of the National Bipartisan Commission on Central America. (Washington, D.C.:U.S. Goverment Printing Office, 1984).
Krauss, C. Inside Central America. (New York: Summit Books, 1992).
Landsberg, M. Export-led Industrialization in the Third World: Manufacturing Imperialism. Review of Radical Political Economics, 11, 1979, 50-63.
Leon, A. Central American Report 1995. (Guatemala: Inforpress, 1995).
Lizano, E. Tres Ensayos sobre Centroamerica. (San Jose, Costa Rica: FLACSO, 1993).
Levy, M. Social Patterns and Problems of Modernization. (Englewood Cliffs, New Jersey: Prentice-Hall,1967).
Liz, R. Crecimiento Economico, Empleo y Capacitacion. (Buenos Aires, Argentina: PNUD, 1993).
Lopez, J. Deuda Externa, Politicas de Estabilizacion y Ajuste Estructural en Centroamerica y Panama. (San Jose, Costa Rica: CSUCA, 1990).
Martinez, M. Democracias de Fachada. (San Jose, Costa Rica: FLACSO, 1991).
McClelland, D. Bussiness Drive and National Achievement. (New York: Basic Books, 1964).
Moore, M. Globalization and Social Change. (New York: Elseiver, 1993).
Moreno, D. The Struggle for Peace in Central America. (Gainsville, Florida: University Press of Florida, 1994).
Nath, B. The Sociology and Politics of Development: A Theoretical Study. (London: Routledge & Kegan Paul, 1990).
Perez, J. Globalizacion y Fuerza Laboral en Centroamerica. (San Jose, Costa Rica: FLACSO, 1993).
Pico, J. Teorias sobre el Estado de Bienestar. (Madrid, España: Siglo XXI editores, 1995).
Portes, A. Labor, Class, and the International System. (New York: Aberdeen, 1992).
Poulantzas, N. Estado y Sociedad en Naciones Dependientes. (Mexico: Siglo XXI editores, 1989).
Prebisch, R. The Economic Development of Latin America and Its Principal Problems. (New York:United Nations, 1950).
Preston, P. Theories of Development. (London: Routledge & Kegan Paul, 1991).
Ragan, J. Principles of Economics. (New York: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich, Publs., 1991).
Ramirez, N. Pobreza y Procesos Sociodemograficos en Republica Dominicana. (Buenos Aires, Argentina: PNUD, 1993).
Razeto, L. Economia de Solidaridad y Mercado Democratico. (Santiago, Chile: Academia de Humanismo, 1995).
Redfield, R. Peasant Society and Culture. (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1965).
Rodriguez, E. Deuda Externa: El Caso de los Pequeños Paises Latinoamericanos. (San Jose, Costa Rica: Banco Centroamericano de Integracion Economica, 1989).
Rosa, H. AID y las transformaciones globales en El Salvador. (Managua, Nicaragua: CRIES, 1993).
Ruben, R. Mas Alla del Ajuste: La Contribucion Europea al Desarrollo en Centroamerica. (San Jose, Costa Rica: DEI, 1991).
Saca, N. Politica de Estabilization y Deuda Externa. (San Salvador, El Salvador: UCA, 1991).
Samuelson, P. Principios de Economia. (Mexico: Fondo de Cultura Economica, 1990).
Sethuraman, V. The Urban Informal Sector in Developing Countries. (Geneva: International Labour Office, 1991).
Smelser, N. Toward a Theory of Modernization. (New York: Basic Books, 1964).
So, A. Social Change and Development. (Newbury Park, California: SAGE, 1991).
So, A. The South China Silk District. (Albany, New York: SUNY Press, 1986).
Stirton, F. Inside the Volvano: The History and Political Economy of Central America. (Boulder,Colorado: Westview Press, 1994).
Tipps, D. Modenization Theory and the Comparative Study of Societies: A critical perspective. (New York: Free Press, 1976).
Torres-Rivas, E. Centroamerica: Las democracias posibles. (San Jose, Costa Rica: FLACSO, 1990).
Torres-Rivas, E. Interpretacion del Desarrollo Social Centroamericano. (San Jose, Costa Rica: EDUCA, 1993).
Vaitsos, C. Una Estrategia Integral para el Desarrollo. (Santo Domingo, Republica Dominicana: PNUD, 1992).
Vuskovic, P. Pequeños Paises Perifericos en America Latina. (Managua, Nicaragua: CRIES, 1990).
Wallerstein, I. Africa: The Politics of Unity. (New York: Random House, 1977).
Wallerstein, I. World-System Analysis. (Standford: Standford University Press, 1987).
Weber, M. The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism. (New York: Scribner, 1988).
Weinberg, B. War on the Land. (London: Zed Books Ltd., 1991).
Zolo, D. Democracia y Complejidad. Un enfoque realista. (Buenos Aires, Argentina: Nueva Visión,1994).
------------------------------0-------------------------------
[1] See Pico, J. Teorias sobre el Estado de Bienestar. (Madrid, España: Siglo XXI editores, 1995), pp. 32-41.; and Razeto, L. Economia de Solidaridad y Mercado Democratico. (Santiago, Chile: Academia de Humanismo, 1995), pp. 56-61.
[2] So, A. Social Change and Development. (Newbury Park, California: SAGE, 1991), pp. 17-23. Liz, R. Crecimiento Economico, Empleo y Capacitacion. (Buenos Aires, Argentina: PNUD, 1993),pp. 27-32.
[3]
Chirot, D. Social Change in a Peripheral Society: The creation of a Balkan colony. (New York: Academic
Press, 1993), pp. 32-34; 56-59. Ramirez, N. Pobreza y Procesos Sociodemograficos en Republica
Dominicana. (Buenos Aires, Argentina: PNUD, 1993), pp. 34-42.
[4]
See Smelser, N. Toward a Theory of Modernization. (New York: Basic
Books, 1964), pp. 268-274.
[5]
Ibid, pp. 276-278.
[6]
Levy, M. Social Patterns and Problems of
Modernization. (Englewood Cliffs, New
Jersey: Prentice-Hall, 1967), pp. 189-207.
[7] Tipps, D.
Modenization Theory and the Comparative Study of Societies:
A critical perspective. (New
York: Free Press, 1976), pp. 65-77.
[8] See Huntington, S. The Change to Change: Modernization, development and politics. (New York: Free Press, 1976), pp. 30-31; 45-52.
[10] Hermassi, E. Changing Patterns in Research on the Third World, Annual Review of Sociology 4, 1978, 239-257.
[12] McClelland, D. Bussiness Drive and National Achievement. (New York: Basic Books, 1964), pp. 167-170.
[13] See, So. Op.Cit. pp. 89, and Vaitsos, C. Una Estrategia Integral para el Desarrollo. (Santo Domingo, Republica Dominicana: PNUD, 1992), pp. 45-53.
[14] Killing, J. The Quest for Economic Stabilization: The IMF and the Third World. (London: Overseas Development Institute, 1984), pp. 45-56.
[15] Redfield, R. Peasant Society and Culture. (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1965), pp. 35-43.
[17] See Bodenheimer, S. Dependency and Imperialism: The roots of Latin American underdevelopment. (New York: NACLA, 1970), pp. 49-53.
[18] Prebisch, R. The Economic Development of Latin America and Its Principal Problems. (New York: United Nations, 1950).
[21] Foster-Carter, A. Neo-Marxist Approaches to Development and Underdevelopment. Journal of Contemporary Asia 3, 1973, 7-33.
[22] Friedrichs, R. A Sociology of Sociology. (New York: Free Press, 1970), pp. 34-36.
[23] Frank, G. Capitalism and Underdevelopment in Latin America. (New York: Monthly Review Press, 1967).
[24]
Frank, G. Latin America: Underdevelopment and Revolution. (New York: Monthly Review Press, 1969).
[25]
Landsberg, M. Export-led Industrialization
in the Third World: Manufacturing
Imperialism. Review
of Radical Political Economics, 11, 1979, 50-63.
[26] Dos Santos, T. Op. Cit.
[27]
Cardoso, F. and Falleto, E. Dependency and
Development in Latin America. (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1979). Fagen, R. Theories
of Development: The question of class
strugle. Monthly Review 35, 1983, 13-24.
[28] Poulantzas, N. Estado
y Sociedad en Naciones Dependientes. (Mexico: Siglo XXI editores, 1989). Pp 56-67; 78-83; 101-112. Alford, R. Los
Poderes de la Teoria. Capitalismo, estado y
democracia. (Buenos Aires, Argentina: Editorial Manantial, 1991).
[29]So,
A. Social
Change and Development, Op.Cit. pp.46-49.
[30] Bergesen, A. Long Waves of Colonial Expansion and Contraction in Studies of the Modern World-System. (New York: Academic Press, 1984). Goldfrank, W. The World-System of Capitalism: Past, and Present. (Beverlly Hills, California: SAGE, 1986).
[32]
Wallerstein, I. Africa: The Politics of Unity. (New York: Random
House, 1977).
[33]
So, A. Op. Cit. Pp. 110-116.
[34] Wallerstein, I. (1987), Op. Cit. Akzin, B. Estado
y Nacion. (Mexico: Fondo de Cultura Economica, 1988). Bell, D. El
Advenimiento de la Sociedad Post-Industrial.
(Madrid: Ed. Alianza, 1987).
[35] Kaplan, B. Social Change in the Capitalist World. (Beverly Hills, California: SAGE, 1993). Gough, I. Economia
Politica del Estado de Bienestar. (Madrid,
España: Blume, 1992).
[36] Moore, M. Globalization and Social Change. (New York: Elseiver,
1993). Isuani, E. El
Estado Benefactor. Un Paradigma en Crisis. (Buenos Aries, Argentina: Miño y Davila, 1991).
[37] Portes, A. Labor, Class, and the International System. (New York: Aberdeen,
1992). Held, D. Modelos de Democracia. (Madrid, España:
Alianza Editorial, 1992).
[38]
Weber, M. The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism. (New York: Scribner,
1988).
[39]
Etzioni. E.
Social Change. (New York: Basic
Books, 1991). Galbraith, J. La Cultura de la Satisfaccion. (Buenos
Aires: Ariel, 1992). Hirschman, A.
De la Economia a la Politica y Mas alla. (Mexico: Fondo
de Cultura Economica, 1987).
Return to Sincronía General Index
Return to Sincronía Winter 2001